- Home
- W Brian Arthur
Complexity and the Economy
Complexity and the Economy Read online
Complexity and the Economy
Other Titles by W. Brian Arthur:
The Nature of Technology: What It Is and How It Evolves
The Economy as an Evolving Complex System II
(co-edited with D. Lane and S. Durlauf)
Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy
Complexity
and the Economy
W. Brian Arthur
1
1
Oxford University Press is a department of the University of
Oxford. It furthers the University’s objective of excellence in research,
scholarship, and education by publishing worldwide.
Oxford New York
Auckland Cape Town Dar es Salaam Hong Kong Karachi
Kuala
Lumpur Madrid Melbourne Mexico
City Nairobi
New
Delhi Shanghai Taipei Toronto
With offices in
Argentina Austria Brazil Chile Czech
Republic France Greece
Guatemala Hungary Italy Japan Poland Portugal Singapore
South
Korea Switzerland Thailand Turkey Ukraine Vietnam
Oxford is a registered trademark of Oxford University Press
in the UK and certain other countries.
Published in the United States of America by
Oxford University Press
198 Madison Avenue, New York, NY 10016
© Oxford University Press 2015
All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in
a retrieval system, or transmitted, in any form or by any means, without the prior permission in writing of Oxford University Press, or as expressly permitted by law, by license, or under terms agreed with the appropriate reproduction rights organization.
Inquiries concerning reproduction outside the scope of the above should be sent to the Rights Department, Oxford University Press, at the address above.
You must not circulate this work in any other form
and you must impose this same condition on any acquirer.
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data
Arthur, W. Brian.
Complexity and the economy / W. Brian Arthur.
pages cm
Includes bibliographical references and index.
ISBN 978–0–19–933429–2
1. Evolutionary economics. 2. Economics–Psychological aspects.
3. Economics. 4. Technological complexity. I. Title.
HB97.3.A78 2015
330.01′511352—dc23
2014012789
9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1
Printed in the United States of America
on acid-free paper
To Brid, Sean, Niamh, and Ronan
CONTENTS
Preface ix
Acknowledgments xxiii
1. Complexity Economics: A Different Framework
for Economic Thought 1
2. Inductive Reasoning and Bounded Rationality: The
El Farol Problem 30
3. Asset Pricing under Endogenous Expectations in an Artificial
Stock Market 39
W. Brian Arthur, John H. Holland, Blake LeBaron, Richard Palmer,
and Paul Tayler
4. Competing Technologies, Increasing Returns, and Lock-In
by Historical Events 69
5. Process and Emergence in the Economy 89
W. Brian Arthur, Steven N. Durlauf, and David A. Lane
6. All Systems Will Be Gamed: Exploitive Behavior in Economic
and Social Systems 103
7. The Evolution of Technology within a Simple Computer Model 119
W. Brian Arthur and Wolfgang Polak
8. The Economy Evolving as Its Technologies Evolve 134
9. On the Evolution of Complexity 144
10. Cognition: The Black Box of Economics 158
11. The End of Certainty in Economics 171
12. Complexity and the Economy 182
An Historical Footnote 189
Other Papers on Complexity and the Economy 193
Index 195
[ viii ] Contents
PREFACE
Every so often a discipline gets thrown into a period of upheaval where its
old ideas once taken for granted seem no longer so reliable, and its practitioners search for what to put in their place. Economics is in such a period now.
This is partly due to the financial crisis of 2008, but the rethinking goes back to well before this. Slowly, over the last three or more decades, a feeling has grown among economists that their key assumptions of perfect rationality,
equilibrium, diminishing returns, and of independent agents always facing
well-defined problems are somehow not trustworthy, too restrictive, some-
how forced. Now in the air are ideas of behavioral rationality, nonequilibrium, increasing returns, and of interconnected agents facing fundamental uncertainty in problems of decision-making. Economics has opened up to other
approaches besides the standard neoclassical one.
I have been heavily involved in one of the new approaches, complexity eco-
nomics, so I decided this would be a good time to put together several of my
earlier papers and bring them out in a collected volume. This collection, on
complexity and the economy, dates from the mid-1980s to the present, and
it follows my earlier one on increasing returns and path dependence in the
economy.1
None of these “new” ideas of course are really completely that new.
Separately and in various forms they have been mooted by economists for
years, sometimes even for a century or more. But what has been missing
was the means to handle them, not just raw techniques but the mindset that
would go with them, that the world is not perfect, that it isn’t machine-like, and that much of it cannot be reduced to simple equations—to variations in
the number or level of entities. And missing too was a coherent framework for
economics based on these new ideas.
In the last few decades this has changed. The missing pieces have begun
to fill in and techniques have slowly become available that can deal with the
new assumptions. Among these are nonlinear dynamics, nonlinear stochastic
1. Increasing Returns and Path Dependence in the Economy, W. B. Arthur, University of Michigan Press, 1994.
processes, agent-based computation, and computational theory itself. The mindset too has changed. A feeling now runs across the sciences, and economics too, that the world is not a perfectly ordered system reducible in principle to mathematical equations, but is to a large extent organic and algorithmic—
it proceeds by building on what is there already and it builds and changes step by step. Slowly, as a result of these occurrences, economics is developing an
approach based on these more realistic assumptions. It is developing a new
framework for economic thought.
The collected papers in this book reflect my part in the development of
this new framework. Taken together they view the economy as a system not
necessarily in equilibrium, but as one where agents constantly change their
actions and strategies in response to the outcome they mutually create, a sys-
tem where agents are constantly creating an “ecology” of behaviors they must
mutually adapt to. This viewpoint has roots of course in complexity thinking
as it developed in the 1970s in groups in Brussels, Stuttgart, and Ann Arbor.
And it has roots in the work of individual researchers in universities such as Stanford and MIT. But in its current economic form it grew largely from work
at the Santa Fe Institute. In the late 1980s a small group of researchers at
the nascent Santa Fe Institute began systematically to look at the economy as
an evolving complex system. I headed that group for its first two years, and
have been associated with it ever since, and in this collection of papers I want to show how these ideas developed and how the economics they led to came
about.
The papers in this volume were not the outcome of some planned process.
They arose haltingly and over several years, and were heavily influenced by
my colleagues and by thinking in general at Santa Fe. Several appeared in
well-known journals, others appeared in places more obscure. Many were
written in Santa Fe, others were written at Stanford. The papers present fin-
ished thinking but not why or how that thinking came about, so it will be
helpful to the reader to understand the background to them and the context
in which they arose.
Most of them started with a single incident.
In April 1987 I was walking toward my office in Stanford when a helmeted
Kenneth Arrow swung round me on his bicycle and stopped. He was putting
together a group of economic theorists in September to exchange ideas with
a group of scientists that his counterpart, physicist Philip Anderson, would
propose. The venue would be a small institute in the Rockies just starting up.
It was in Santa Fe. Would I like to come? I said yes immediately without being sure of what I was committing myself to. The idea looked promising.
The conference in Santa Fe when I got there a few months later turned out
to be a more heavyweight affair than I’d imagined. Among the ten or so econ-
omists Arrow chose were Larry Summers, Tom Sargent, Jose Sheinkman, and
[ x ] Preface
William (Buz) Brock. Among the ten or so scientists Phil Anderson chose were John Holland, David Ruelle, Stuart Kauffman, and David Pines. The
meeting was held in the chapel of a convent the new institute was renting
and there was nothing rushed about it. A participant would talk in the morn-
ing and we would discuss, another participant would talk in the afternoon
and again we would discuss. We were learning not just solutions to problems
in the others’ disciplines, but about what each discipline saw as a problem,
and how it thought about these, and what mindset it brought to bear on
these problems. Questions not normally raised within economics were
raised—why do you guys cling onto perfect rationality? Why do you assume
so much linearity? And questions were asked of physics too. Why is a prob-
lem “solved,” say in spin glasses, when it has not settled to a steady state?
Chaos theory and nonlinear dynamics were discussed in both economics and
physics. Modeling of positive feedbacks and of interactions, again in both
disciplines, was discussed. People would meet at night in twos and threes to
talk over ideas and problems.
The meeting was exhilarating—and exhausting. Nothing had quite been
solved by the end of the ten days, yet the physics side was left with a respect for the sheer complicatedness of the economy—the elements in the economy
(people), unlike the ions in a lattice, could decide what to do next not just
based on the current situation of themselves and other elements, but on what
they thought those other elements might do given what they might do. And the economists were left with a feeling for modern physics, for its interactions and nonlinearities, its multiple possible end states, its lack of predictability—
indeed for its complicatedness.
Word began to leak out after the conference that something interesting
had happened at Santa Fe and the new institute’s Science Board decided it
would follow the conference up by initiating a long-term research program
on the Economy as an Evolving Complex System. John Holland and I were
asked to come to Santa Fe the following year to head this. I had a sabbatical
coming from Stanford and accepted, John found it harder to get away from
Michigan and declined. So I found myself heading up the Santa Fe Institute’s
first research program; it would start in August the following year, 1988.
My immediate problem of course, working from Stanford, was to put
together a team of first-rate people for the new program and to decide its
direction. Some people I already knew from the conference. John Holland
promised to come for a couple of months, and the physicist Richard Palmer for
much longer than that. Stuart Kauffman would be in residence. From my own
network I was able to bring in David Lane and Yuri Ermoliev, both excellent
probability theorists. Arrow and Anderson helped greatly. Where I found it
hard to cajole people to join in, Arrow or Anderson, both Nobel Prize winners, could simply lift the phone and quickly get people to join us. As to direction I was less sure. Early on, the physicist Murray Gell-Mann suggested to me that Pr eface [ xi ]
we come up with a manifesto for doing economics differently. I didn’t quite have the confidence for that; in fact I didn’t yet know what topics we would
go after. I had done quite a bit of work already on complexity and the econ-
omy, but now we had a much broader reach in what topics we might research.
From the conference it was assumed that chaos theory would be central, but
the idea somehow didn’t appeal to me. Vaguely I thought that we should look
at increasing returns problems, which I was more than familiar with, at how
some of the physics methods could be transferred into economics, and at non-
linear dynamics in the economy. Also we might be able to do something inter-
esting with computation in economics.
When the program opened finally in 1988 we discussed directions further,
still groping for a way forward. I phoned Ken Arrow from Santa Fe and asked
for his advice and Phil Anderson’s. They got in touch with the funder of the
program, John Reed of Citibank, and the word came back: Do what you want,
providing it deals with the foundations of economics, and is not conventional.
For me and the others on the team, this directive seemed like a dream. We
had carte blanche to do what we wanted, and at Santa Fe we wouldn’t have
colleagues from the discipline looking at us and asking why we were doing
things differently.
In fact, outside our small team the few colleagues we did have were from
physics or theoretical biology. Stuart Kauffman was one, and we immediately
included him in the program. There was little else in the way of researchers the new institute could offer. It was in its earliest days and was all but unknown, an experiment, a small startup in the Rockies set up to have no students, no
classes, no departments, and no disciplines—no discipline, the wags said.
We had discussions, mainly in the convent’s kitchen, and I remember in
an early one Kauffman said, Why do you guys do everything at equilibrium?
What would it be like to do economics out of equilibrium? Like all economists
I had thought about that, but not seriously. In fact the question took me
aback, and it did so with the other economists. I had no good answer. It fell
into the category of questions such as w
hat would physics be like if the gravitational force were suspended, something that seemed perfectly thinkable as
a thought experiment, but strange. And yet Kauffman’s question stuck. We
retained the question but we were still looking for a direction ahead.
One of the directions that interested me was still half formed. It had come
out of the conference the previous year. In an after-lunch talk the first day of that conference, John Holland had described his work on classifier systems,
basically systems that are concatenations of condition-action rules. One rule
might say that if the system’s environment fulfills condition A, then execute action R. Another might say, if it fulfills condition D, execute action T. A third might say that if A is true, and R-being-executed is not true, then execute action Z. And so on. The actions taken would change the environment, the
[ xii ] Preface
overall state of the system. In this way you could string such if-then rules together to get a system to “recognize” its environment and execute actions
appropriately, much as an E. coli bacterium “recognizes” a glucose gradient in its environment and swims in an appropriate direction. Moreover, you could
allow the system to start with not-so-good rules and replace these with better ones it discovered over time. The system could learn and evolve.
As Holland talked about this I found myself deeply excited, and I checked
the room to see if other economists were similarly taken with these ideas.
There was no evidence; in fact one of them was taking a post-lunch nap. A feeling grew in me that somehow, in some way, this was an answer and all we
had to do was find the question. Somehow Holland was describing a method
whereby “intelligence” or appropriate action could automatically evolve
within systems. I quizzed John later about his ideas. We were sharing a house
in Santa Fe for two months at that time in 1987, but in several conversations
neither of us could work out what these ideas might directly have to do with
economics.
I had gone back to Stanford, where I was teaching a course in economic